Three Facets of Political Inequality

Evidence from Consultative Processes in Kampala

Constantin Manuel Bosancianu

WZB Berlin

Macartan Humphreys

Columbia & WZB Berlin

Ana Garcia-Hernandez

J-PAL Europe

Overview

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Quick glance: Developing Kampala’s Citizen Charter

Scope: Kampala, Uganda | 2,312 residents | 188 small-scale citizen meetings

Duration: Jan. 2019 – Dec. 2022 (pandemic interruptions)

Implementation: IPA Uganda

Funders: IGC, WZB, Columbia, an anonymous foundation

Goal: Provide citizen input into the construction of a Citizen Charter in Kampala, outlining rights and responsibilities between citizens and municipality

Results based on baseline survey, consultation behavior and decisions, and post-consultation survey.

The context

  1. Challenges of service delivery among a rapidly-growing urban population
  2. Issues of institutional accountability: KCCA (city hall) is a new institution operating in a constrained context
  3. Institutional volatility: frequent leadership changes (KCCA head appointed by President)

Present at the birth of a new institution in the city: a Charter.

Primary goal: measurement of political inequality

How can we best measure citizens’ degree of political power (understood as influence)? How much inequality is there in this?

How do gaps in voice (Coffe and Bolzendahl 2011; Kasara and Suryanarayan 2015) relate to systemic responsiveness (Gaikwad and Nellis 2021)?

Probe complex linkages between:

  1. input: inequality in intensity of participation
  2. throughput: inequality in the system’s responsiveness to demands
  3. output: inequality in how much decisions favor specific individuals / groups

Preview of findings

We uncover clear disparities in inputs, with more advantaged citizens participating more during meetings.

There is evidence of limited elite capture, but not of outright throughput inequality between groups.

Thankfully, no evidence of output inequalities, suggesting the possibility of effective compartmentalization.

Even in a “hard case” (trained facilitators, small group, grounded topics) we continue to observe input inequality.

Where does discrepancy come from?

Inequality in participation and preferences \(\nrightarrow\) inequality in outputs.

Our interpretation: evidence consistent with discussion leaders countervailing efforts by more powerful groups to skew outcomes.

Possible means:

  • imposing their own views on discussions
  • amplifying opinion of less powerful groups (some evidence for this)

What do you think could be happening?

Theoretical framework

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Simple model of political action

We start from a simple model: a status quo policy, \(x\), which \(N\) players with ideal policy points \(x_i^*\) try to influence.

Each player takes action with intensity \(a_i^*\), and with \(\pi_i^*\) denoting how much their action would shape the outcome (causal quantity).

Utility is: \(u_{i} = -(x_{i}^{*} - x^{'})^2 - a_{i}^2\)

The new policy is the result of all individual actions: \(x^{'} = x + \sum_{i=1}^{N}\pi_ia_i\)

Players choose optimal actions, which can vary in direction and magnitude, and we seek a Nash equilibrium.

Similar to the Esteban and Ray (1999) model, though on a policy space.

Strategies depend on other actors

The best response of player \(i\) is:

\[ a_i = \frac{\pi_i(x^*_i - x)}{1+\pi_i^2} - \frac{\pi_i\sum_{-i}\pi_{j} a_{j}}{1+\pi_i^2} \]

Important to note that action taken by \(i\) depends on:

  1. own effectiveness, \(\pi_i\)
  2. the action of \(j\): \(a_j\)
  3. the effectiveness of \(j\): \(\pi_j\)

Also tied to own dissatisfaction with reversion point, and extremity to others’ preferences.

Multiple forms of inequality

In equilibrium, welfare is:

\[ w_i = -(1+\pi^2_i)\left(\frac{(x^*_i - x) + \sum_j(x^*_i - x^*_j)\pi_j^2}{1+\sum_j\pi_j^2}\right)^2 \]

We can have inequality in:

  1. inputs
  2. throughput
  3. outputs

These are distinct quantities, and inter-related in complex ways depending on where the status quo, x, is.

Illustration: complex dynamics

Ideals are fixed: \(x_1 = -0.5\) and \(x_2 = 0.5\)

Increases in input inequality sometimes result in corresponding increases in output inequality, but sometimes they don’t.

Capturing the dynamics

We try to assess these inequalities in the setting of our consultative meetings.

They allow us to measure:

  1. preferences
  2. the actions taken to promote these
  3. outcomes (decisions)

We sacrifice some generalizability, but gain tight control over the process and the possibility to measure frequently.

Implementation

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Treatment: assigned to consultation

Balance: T1 vs. T0 | Balance: \(T1_1\) vs. \(T1_2\) | Sampling | Areas sampled | Factorial design

Structure of meetings

  • Small-scale consultation meetings, of around 1-1.5 hours
  • Participants: 6-8 citizens recruited from the same village
  • Facilitated by KCCA officials, or neutral facilitators (trained enumerators)
  • Objective: collect input from citizens for construction of Charter
  • Decisions: made by the group, and recorded by facilitator

Neutral facilitators underwent a special training focused on the importance of neutrality in such consultations.

Topics discussed in meetings

  1. Report municipal expenditures: At what levels should budgets be reported to citizens?
  2. Channels of communication: Through what communication channels should KCCA engage with citizens?
  3. City allocations: growth vs equality: Should KCCA plan city investments focusing on maximizing growth or reducing inequality?
  4. Raising fees and taxes: Should there be higher taxes for better services, or rather lower taxes even with fewer services?
  5. Monitoring Charter: Should Charter be monitored externally or internally?
  6. Extra: “Is KCCA going in the right direction?”

Features: (1) identified based on baseline survey; (2) vetted by KCCA; (3) plausibly contentious.

Disagreement: citizens vs. KCCA

We also observe preference variation among citizens: disagreement

Mapping: questions-data

Component Data used
Political behaviors reported in baseline survey
Input inequality Attendance
Participation patterns during consultation
Facilitator preferences over consultation outcomes
Throughput inequality Consultation outcomes
Citizen preferences over consultation outcomes
Attendance
Output inequality Citizen preferences over consultation outcomes
Facilitator preferences over consultation outcomes

Dimensions of inequality we probe

Among citizens:

  1. Gender
  2. Language (Luganda)
  3. Age
  4. Education
  5. Wealth

Between citizens and facilitators: Who exerts more influence over final outcome?

Results: Input Inequality

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Inequality in conventional participation

Gender: +1SD designates men. Luganda: +1SD designates native speakers.

Attendance to meetings

Inequality during consultations: times spoken

Distribution of outcome

Inequality during consultations: total time spoken

Distribution of outcome

Is there input inequality?

Input inequality is clearly present, both for conventional political activities and for consultation meetings.

This is matched by meaningful differences in pre-meeting preferences: Example 1 | Example 2 | Example 3

Attendance to meetings is more equal (efforts to mobilize), but inside consultations established patterns re-emerge.

Results: Throughput Inequality

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Effect of leaders: KCCA going in right direction?

Facilitators in general, and IPA facilitators in particular, matter!

We see a similar visible difference for 2 more topics.

Do facilitators drive outcomes?

Adj. \(R^2\): bound on the degree influence . Facilitators drive 10–25% of variation in meeting outcomes.

Are they more influential in disadv. contexts?

Interaction effect: Facilitator pref. x Advantaged
Topic Estimate SE p
Budget reporting level 0.020 0.060 0.747
Channels of communication -0.125 0.199 0.548
Growth vs. equality 0.011 0.018 0.550
Fees vs. more KCCA services -0.123 0.131 0.387
Monitoring of Charter 0.066 0.074 0.393
Note: clustered SEs reported
1 Unit of analysis is meeting decision. 2 All analyses clustered at the facilitator level. 3 Significance test conducted at the 90% level 4 N = 188 decisions.

The dynamic we expect is not seen for any of the topics.

Facilitator preferences do not drive the meeting outcome more in disadvantaged communities.

KCCA vs. IPA facilitators: is there outcome skew?

For one of five issues, we see outcomes skewed in a direction preferred by the institution (KCCA).

Do the disadvantaged do worse under some facilitators?

Example: \(Match_i = \beta_0 + \beta_1*gender + \beta_2*KCCA + {\color{purple}{\beta_3}}*gender*KCCA + \epsilon_i\)

No: we don’t see inequality in responsiveness.

Is there throughput inequality?

We find clear influence of facilitators in the process: anywhere between 10 and 25% (of variance in outcomes explained by facilitator identity).

For only one issue, clear differences in outcomes between KCCA and IPA facilitators.

No evidence that the preferences of some sub-groups are favored over those of other sub-groups.

Results: Output Inequality

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Disadvantaged less likely to get favored outcome?

\(Match_i = \beta_0 + {\color{purple}{\beta_1}}*gender + \beta_2*attended + \beta_3*gender*attended + \epsilon_i\)

Results for education | Results for wealth

Effects of meetings: satisfaction with outcomes?

Is there output inequality?

No evidence of output inequality for any of the discussion topics. If anything, more advantaged report being less happy with outcomes.

Some effects of socio-demographics, but of inconsistent direction.

No disparity in effect of socio-demographics depending on participation in meetings.

What explains outcomes?

Why the discrepancy: input \(\nrightarrow\) responsiveness?

Evidence that facilitators may act to ensure one powerful group (men) doesn’t dominate discussions.

Structural model

Conclusions

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Summing up

We find consistent patterns of input inequality during on consultations (by gender, age, wealth, and education), but not in attendance at consultations.

Discussion facilitators have a moderately-strong influence over the outcome of the consultation (some evidence of throughput inequality, but no disparities in responsiveness).

Encouragingly, we find no systematic evidence of output inequality.

Egalitarian process partly offset by inequalities in power.

Implications

Lijphart (1997): unequal participation produces unequal responsiveness (Hill and Leighley 1992). Might not always be the case.

A mistake to infer inequality in outcomes from inequality in inputs, or inequality in responsiveness from inequality in inputs.

In our setting, we believe facilitators play an offsetting role—what else could be at play?

Thank you for the kind attention!

Appendices

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Equality in meeting participation

Participation dynamics

Meetings vs. pure control

Balance table: pure control vs. meetings
Factor Mean control Mean meetings Diff. mean SE diff. p 95% CI low 95% CI high
Gender (male) 0.54 0.54 0.00 0.02 0.84 -0.03 0.04
Age 34.76 34.61 -0.15 0.62 0.81 -1.38 1.08
Luganda 0.56 0.52 -0.04 0.03 0.21 -0.10 0.02
Education 11.03 11.00 -0.03 0.22 0.89 -0.47 0.40
Wealth 1.12 1.14 0.02 0.06 0.79 -0.10 0.13
Index of advantage 0.00 0.00 -0.01 0.01 0.54 -0.03 0.02
Political efficacy 2.82 2.80 -0.02 0.05 0.77 -0.12 0.09
Pro-sociality 16.71 16.42 -0.29 1.44 0.84 -3.13 2.56
Note: N = 2,429
1 N control = 773. 2 N meetings = 1,656. Of these, 1,539 were originally invited to attend, and were 117 recruited again from villages where no meeting could be organized.

Design

IPA vs. KCCA meetings

Balance table: IPA vs. KCCA meetings
Factor Mean IPA Mean KCCA Diff. mean SE diff. p 95% CI low 95% CI high
Gender (male) 0.54 0.54 0.00 0.02 0.88 -0.04 0.05
Age 34.75 35.00 0.25 0.74 0.73 -1.20 1.71
Luganda 0.54 0.54 0.01 0.04 0.87 -0.07 0.08
Education 10.91 10.98 0.08 0.30 0.80 -0.51 0.66
Wealth 1.08 1.16 0.08 0.07 0.27 -0.06 0.22
Index of advantage -0.01 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.35 -0.02 0.04
Political efficacy 2.83 2.78 -0.05 0.06 0.40 -0.17 0.07
Pro-sociality 15.17 17.43 2.26 1.79 0.21 -1.27 5.79

Design

Baseline sampling

Sampling frame for one village

Final sample for the village

Design

Areas sampled

Design

Realized sample

Sampling plan vs. reality
N planned N realized
T0: Control Villages 96 97
Individuals 768 773
T1(1): Neutral consultations Villages 96 93
Individuals 768 745
T1(2): KCCA-led consultations Villages 96 95
Individuals 768 761
TOTAL Villages 288 285
Individuals 2304 2312

Design

Total no. of uninvited contributions

Inequality in participation

Disagreement: citizens vs. citizens

Disagreement with KCCA

Total time spent speaking

Inequality in participation

Preferences for raising fees and taxes

Fees and taxes in the city
Factor Est. SE p R squared N
Gender (male) 0.013 0.029 0.652 0.000 2417
Age -0.075 0.029 0.010 0.003 2417
Luganda -0.067 0.028 0.017 0.002 2417
Education 0.173 0.028 0.000 0.016 2417
Wealth 0.113 0.027 0.000 0.007 2409
Index of advantage 0.199 0.053 0.000 0.006 2409
Note: clustered SEs reported
1 Outcome is measured on a 3-point scale: 1 = lower fees and taxes, but fewer services; 2 = keep fees and taxes the same; 3 = raise fees and taxes, but more services. 2 Specifications are univariate linear models, with socio-demographic factors included one by one. 3 Clustering performed at the level of villages.

Input inequality

Preferences for channels of communication

Channels of citizen-KCCA communication
Factor Est. SE p R squared N
Gender (male) 0.018 0.029 0.551 0.000 2423
Age -0.130 0.028 0.000 0.008 2423
Luganda -0.044 0.031 0.154 0.001 2423
Education 0.199 0.030 0.000 0.020 2423
Wealth 0.213 0.032 0.000 0.023 2414
Index of advantage 0.336 0.057 0.000 0.016 2414
Note: clustered SEs reported
1 Outcome is measured on a 3-point scale: 1 = in-person meetings in the villages; 2 = drop-in centers at district city halls; 3 = social media channels. 2 Specifications are univariate linear models, with socio-demographic factors included one by one. 3 Clustering performed at the level of villages.

Input inequality

Preferences for budget reporting level

Channels of citizen-KCCA communication
Factor Est. SE p R squared N
Gender (male) -0.027 0.030 0.372 0.000 2416
Age 0.025 0.029 0.397 0.000 2416
Luganda 0.068 0.030 0.024 0.002 2416
Education -0.079 0.031 0.012 0.003 2416
Wealth -0.088 0.032 0.007 0.004 2407
Index of advantage -0.115 0.058 0.047 0.002 2407
Note: clustered SEs reported
1 Outcome is measured on a 3-point scale: 1 = district level (status quo); 2 = parish level; 3 = village level. 2 Specifications are univariate linear models, with socio-demographic factors included one by one. 3 Clustering performed at the level of villages.

Input inequality

Effect of education

Output inequality

Effect of wealth

Output inequality

Using framework to directly estimate power

\[ a_i^* = \frac{\pi_i}{1 + \sum_j\pi_j^2}\left((x^*_i - x)+ \sum_j(\pi_j^2(x^*_i - x_j^*))\right) \]

\(\pi\) conceptualized as function of interplay between gender and wealth.

Goal is to retrieve parameters that govern one’s level of political power in consultations.

Power in consultations

Output inequality

What explains outcomes?

A puzzling feature of the data: neither facilitator preferences nor those of participants seem to structure outcomes.

We try to let the data speak by itself in search of the factors that do, by using BART (Bayesian Additive Regression Trees)

  1. Non-parametric approach which is good at capturing linear and non-linear effects, as well as higher-order interactions
  2. Produces measures of uncertainty (due to the Bayesian estimation)
  3. Performs well in cases where the \(n/k\) ratio is low (Chipman, George, and McCulloch 2010)

Unlike typical ML applications, we use the entire sample during the training (model calibration) stage.

Top 4 explanatory factors (permutation-based)

Communication channels Monitoring Charter Fees and taxes Budget priorities Reporting budget KCCA right direction
Meeting duration V. mean age F. age % women in meeting F. language V. mean satisf. with KCCA
F. age V. mean preference for monitoring V. mean preference for fees F. age F. age F. background
F. gender V. mean pol. information % women in meeting F. preference for monitoring F. origin F. language
F. background V. mean comm. engagement V. mean pol. participation V. mean pol. information V. mean education F. age
Note: N = 188 meeting decisions
1 F. denotes a feature of the facilitators. 2 V. denotes a feature of the villages. 3 Village features computed as means of characteristics of baseline participants from a specific village.

Village preferences matter, but not as much as facilitator characteristics.

In the top 8 features, we frequently see political features at the village (political information, engagement, participation) as mattering in 3/6 cases.

Comparative model fit

Predictive accuracy does increase when adding substantive predictors, but only slightly.

Output inequality summary

Bibliography

Chipman, Hugh A., Edward I. George, and Robert E. McCulloch. 2010. BART: Bayesian Additive Regression Trees.” The Annals of Applied Statistics 4 (1): 266–98.
Coffe, Hilde, and Catherine Bolzendahl. 2011. Gender Gaps in Political Participation Across Sub-Saharan African Nations.” Social Indicators Research 102 (2): 245–64.
Esteban, Joan-Maria, and Debraj Ray. 1999. “Conflict and Distribution.” Journal of Economic Theory 87 (2): 379–415.
Gaikwad, Nikhar, and Gareth Nellis. 2021. Do Politicians Discriminate Against Internal Migrants? Evidence from Nationwide Field Experiments in India.” American Journal of Political Science 65 (4): 790–806. https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12548.
Hill, Kim Quaile, and Jan E. Leighley. 1992. The Policy Consequences of Class Bias in State Electorates.” American Journal of Political Science 36 (2): 351–65.
Kasara, Kimuli, and Pavithra Suryanarayan. 2015. When Do the Rich Vote Less Than the Poor and Why? Explaining Turnout Inequality across the World.” American Journal of Political Science 59 (3): 613–27.
Lijphart, Arend. 1997. Unequal Participation: Democracy’s Unresolved Dilemma.” The American Political Science Review 91 (1): 1–14.